Skip to content
(iStockphoto via Getty Images)
(iStockphoto via Getty Images)
AuthorAuthor
PUBLISHED: | UPDATED:

Whenever the interest rate spread between the long 10-year T-Bond and the short 90-day T-Bill has turned negative, it has invariably been followed by a recession. Yet, in spite of the fact that the interest rate spread has been negative for 18 months — the longest in history — there’s been no recession. What happened?

Many would answer this question by asserting that things are different now and that structural shifts in the economy mean that interest rates don’t matter much anymore. In a recent article in the Wall Street Journal, for example, Andy Kessler concludes, “Higher interest rates may matter but for an increasingly smaller portion of our economy.”

One, however, doesn’t have to turn to structural changes in the economy to explain why the economy has continued to grow recession free for two years in the face of a negative interest rate spread and 11 increases in the federal funds rate. A more likely reason to explain this apparent anomaly is old-fashioned Keynesian fiscal stimulus, namely historically high federal deficits.

Between 1947 and 2019, the national deficit — federal spending less federal revenues — averaged 2% of GDP. To fight the COVID recession in 2020, however, the federal deficit as a share of GDP hit an astonishing double-digit rate of 14.7%. That was followed a year later, by a deficit of 11.8%. Since 1953, the highest deficit ever reached in a single year was 9.7% in 2009 during the Great Recession.

While it may be argued that these deficits were necessary to provide the kind of aggressive fiscal stimuli needed to fight the COVID recession, that’s not the case in 2022 and 2023, where the fight isn’t about a recession but about inflation. That kind of fight doesn’t call for fiscal stimulus. Quite the contrary — even John Maynard Keynes would agree — it calls for fiscal contraction. Yet, the federal deficit reached $1.4 trillion in 2022 and $1.7 trillion in 2023. As a share of GDP, these deficits were 5.3% in 2022 and 6.2% in 2023.

Consider the impact of these deficits. In 2022, nominal GDP grew by 9.1% while the GDP price deflator increased by 7.1%. As a result, real GDP after adjusting for inflation, increased by 2.0%. But that same year, the deficit as a share of GDP was 5.3%. As noted above, the average deficit between 1947 and 2019 was 2%. That means the added fiscal stimulus over-and-above the 2% norm was 3.3%. Even without considering any multiplier, the government stimulated the economy by an extra 3.3%. Without that fiscal push, it would have declined by -1.3% rather than growing at 3.3%. That sounds to us like a recession.

The story in 2023 is more of the same. Nominal GDP grew by 6.3%, but after adjusting for inflation, real GDP increased by 2.5%. The deficit that year, however, hit 6.2%. Given the normal deficit of 2.0%, there was an extra-normal stimulus of 4.2%. Without that additional kick to the economy, real GDP would have declined by -1.7%.

These findings show that the normally negative impact of high interest rates has been more than offset by historically high federal deficits. The short-run stimulative effects of those deficits may prove beneficial for a second term of Joe Biden’s presidency. But while deficits pack a punch in the short run, they spell stagflation and higher debt loads in the long run. John Keynes might argue, “In the long run we are all dead.” But the long run, in the current case, isn’t that long. Already in 2024, the economy is beginning to experience withdrawal effects from excessive stimulation.

In spite of a deficit this fiscal year that may run as high as $2 trillion, real GDP grew only 1.6% in the first quarter on an annualized basis. That’s the weakest growth since 2022. In spite of Fed efforts, inflation is picking up steam. As a result, the Fed has postponed cuts in the federal funds rate. Funding escalating deficits requires the issuance of huge amounts of new treasury debt. As a result, long-term rates are increasing again. Mortgage rates are back above 7%, pushing the residential housing sector into recession. Higher long rates are leading to huge writedowns of commercial real estate debt placing the balance sheets of many mid-sized banks in jeopardy. Perhaps most worrisome is that massive deficits come at the expense of private investment. Maybe that tradeoff explains why business investment grew at a paltry 2.1% in the first quarter and that private investment in equipment declined in four quarters over the past two years.

So, while fiscal stimulus has masked recessionary forces, that mask seems to be coming off. Perhaps that explains why, in spite of continuing reports about a strong economy, people feel kind of crummy.

Jim Doti is president emeritus and Rick Muth Family Chair in Economics at Chapman University. Raymond Sfeir is the director of the A. Gary Anderson Center for Economic Research at Chapman University.